Recursive IRV
-
@spelunker No, that is not the same thing. You might as well say that you could skip the top application of Hare and just elect the candidate with the highest plurality score and that would be the same as Hare.
-
The recursive method alternates between looking for a good candidate and looking for the worst candidate.
I have not checked @rob's assertion that just one level of recursion will make the system comply with Condorcet.
-
Now I am fully confused. Would you be able to give a complete (and self-contained) description of the rule? (Pseudocode would also work)
-
@rob , this is kind of the key section of your code for this, right?
doEliminationLoop = (candidates, ballotsExp, isNegative) => { var results = { rounds: [] }; var numCandidates = candidates.length; for(var i=0; i<numCandidates; i++) { var candidatesSorted = // (depth>0) ? //sortedCandidatesByEliminationRounds(candidates, ballotsExp, true, 1) : sortedCandidatesByFirstPlaceVotes(candidates, ballotsExp); console.log(depth + " " + isNegative) console.log(JSON.stringify(candidatesSorted,0,2)) var toBeEliminated = candidatesSorted[(isNegative)?0:candidatesSorted.length-1]; results.rounds.push(candidatesSorted); //setValue('output_2', JSON.stringify(candidatesSorted,0,2)) // maybe use Array.filter? candidates = []; // rebuild array without winner for(var j=0; j<candidatesSorted.length; j++) { if(candidatesSorted[j].name != toBeEliminated.name) { candidates.push(candidatesSorted[j].name); } } } results.winner = results.rounds[results.rounds.length-1][0] return results }
His condition on
isNegative
is key here. He's sorting the candidates the same way, based on top rankings, but he's picking whom to eliminate from the list from either the top or the bottom of the list. -
@spelunker I could be vague on some details and we might need @rob to clarify, unless one of us wants to fully reverse engineer his code and see why it produced different results for the Burlington, Vt. election than what you would predict, @spelunker.
-
This still very much seems like IRV and not Condorcet compliant though. Just imagine you have two voters and three candidates with preferences a>b>c and c>b>a. Wouldn't this method delete b in the first step which was the condorcet winner?
-
Thanks for giving an example to work.
Hare to the zeroth power is choose-one plurality.
Hare to the first power is Hare.
Hare squared does about (n - 1)(n - 1)/2 rounds, concerned with promotion of candidates rather than elimination of them.
I have three candidates and want to get down to two. Whom do I promote first? It's a tie between a and c. I have to appeal to @rob for tiebreaking rules, or make up my own.
Can you give an example that doesn't tie at any stage?
-
@spelunker Hey sorry if my explanation wasn't clear. I actually started to develop a much better version, where you could choose any depth, and (the hard part) it had the ability to show output so it was understandable, but then I messed up and lost my code or something and dropped it for a while. (I'm sure I'll come back to it)
Look at it this way. What IRV attempts to do, prior to doing the final calculation (i.e. "determine who is preferred by more people"), is to remove irrelevant alternatives so the calculation is not affected by them. But it does the elimination rather crudely, based on "negative plurality". (least first choice votes)
This just takes it to another level, using the same logic for the elimination as it does for the final determination. As you go to further and further recursion depths, this should get more and more accurate, as the "crude part" is less and less relevant.
My general hypothesis is that Condorcet compliance is simply an easy to define step on the way to our goal of "immune to vote splitting." IRV logic is obviously closer to this goal than plurality, but since it can result in missing the Condorcet winner, it isn't very far toward the goal. Applying the logic twice appears to make it Condorcet compliant. Applying it 3 or more times moves it ever closer to the goal.
Since it is technically impossible to apply it an infinite number of times, this doesn't violate Arrow's theorem (and the like).
-
@rob This is sort of like engineered chess programs. They look ahead a certain number of moves and then resort to crude heuristics.
The ones that are not "engineered" use connectionism and/or Darwinism, but techniques like that are not relevant here. Before people tried those, they were engineering the solution, i. e. designing it top to bottom by hand.
-
@spelunker said in Recursive IRV:
Just imagine you have two voters and three candidates with preferences a>b>c and c>b>a. Wouldn't this method delete b in the first step which was the condorcet winner?
It might, but I don't consider that a good example since to me it is (or should be) a three way tie.
If you have a case where there are no pairwise ties, and there is a Condorcet winner which it misses, I'd be interested in seeing it.
-
I believe it's a Copeland tie and a Dasgupta-Maskin tie.
a vs. b: no winner.
a vs. c: no winner. c vs. b: no winner.
-|
-
I wonder whether it can be proven that adding more and more layers of recursion eventually converges on a fixed outcome, for any given set of ballots.
-
@jack-waugh said in Recursive IRV:
I wonder whether it can be proven that adding more and more layers of recursion eventually converges on a fixed outcome, for any given set of ballots.
I'd love to see it proven. It seems to me that it is obviously true, but it is beyond my capabilities to actually prove it. Currently I am relying on intuition as well as just testing it on sample data.
-
@rob said in Recursive IRV:
@jack-waugh said in Recursive IRV:
I wonder whether it can be proven that adding more and more layers of recursion eventually converges on a fixed outcome, for any given set of ballots.
I'd love to see it proven. It seems to me that it is obviously true, but it is beyond my capabilities to actually prove it. Currently I am relying on intuition as well as just testing it on sample data.
I could try to prove it, but I might need a more formal definition of the method for it. If possible not in JavaScript
-
@spelunker Is there anything in particular you need explained or clarified?
While my current implementation is javascript, I didn't "write" it so much as prompted ChatGPT to write it, and since I did it very step by step, it should be easy to follow.
Here is the chatGPT conversation: https://sharegpt.com/c/fyOiNHy
It didn't make any mistakes, so it is pretty easy to follow, but I was careful in terms of prompting it to do one thing at a time.Here is the codepen: https://codepen.io/karmatics/pen/KKxeEEJ?editors=1010
First I asked ChatGPT to parse ranked ballots and put them into a reasonable data structure. Then I had it so it could clone that data structure and remove a candidate (from the list of candidates as well as from the ballots), to allow for elimination.
Then I made a function "doPlurality" to do a plurality calculation on that, and return the winner(s) in an array (in case of tie it can be more than one). Then I had that function be able to do it inverted, to find the plurality loser.
Then I had it make a function "doIRV": to do an IRV tabulation on it, which in turn calls the "doPlurality" function multiple times, inverted so it picks the loser so that candidate can be eliminated.
Then I made sure doIRV could be inverted itself.
Finally, I made doIRV so it can recurse to a given depth, which means that, instead of calling doPlurality to find candidates to eliminate, it calls doIRV. (until it reaches the specified depth, when it will call doPlurality) Whether calling doIRV or doPlurality, it always reverses the "findLoser" flag from that sent to the containing function. (you want it to look for "bad" candidates to eliminate, but look for "good" candidates to eliminate from being eliminated, and so on)
I'm not sure what you are looking for as far as a formal definition, but if you need something else please let me know. Between my chatGPT prompts, the actual code, and the running app on CodePen it should be pretty concisely defined.
It would be awesome if you were able to do some kind of proof or at least an analysis.
-
@rob Sorry for being so bothersome. The Javascript function naturally has a lot of overhead, which makes it quite hard to analyse and parse. (For instance, all the data structure overhead is not needed for a pseudocode) Maybe this is just me, though.
-
@spelunker said in Recursive IRV:
Sorry for being so bothersome.
Not at all, I appreciate your taking an interest.
Do you know any programming language? I think the JS implementation is quite nice and clean, as is most of ChatGPTs stuff. It is cleaner than if I wrote it directly, unless I had put a huge amount of effort in. However, if you know python or whatever, I can ask chatGPT to produce a python version. It's quite good at that.
The code could be simplified if I removed the part where it passes back data so we can show a big nested json structure as output. If all you want is a winner, the code would possibly be easier to read, but not easier to follow by running a CodePen since there'd be no output of "process"
That said, the easiest way to follow it is to follow the chatgpt conversation as I prompted it to build it. Not only can you see what I asked it in plain English, it explains the code in plain English.
Do you at least get the main idea? Let me try to put my thoughts into a logical series of statements, starting with the most simple and obvious.
Plurality can be applied to ranked ballots. That is, you can count the first place votes and ignore all the rest.
Plurality voting can be used to find either a "good candidate", or a "bad candidate". The best candidate is defined as having the most first choice votes. The worst is defined as having the fewest first choice votes. (ties are possible and need to be accounted for, but for the rest of this we'll ignore them)
Plurality logic is used within IRV. In this case, it looks for bad candidates, since it needs to eliminate these candidates. So regular IRV could be said to eliminate plurality losers.
IRV can be used to find a bad candidate, just as plurality can. To do this, we eliminate good candidates (plurality winners) one by one. So both Plurality voting, and IRV voting, are able to produce an inverse result (i.e. "loser")
Given that IRV can produce an inverse result, it can be substituted for Plurality within IRV logic. So we can produce a recursive IRV, that calls inverse IRV, to determine who to eliminate. That IRV election, though, calls into Plurality to produce its result. This is one level of recursion.
And we can continue doing this to any depth. If the depth is an odd number (1 being normal IRV, 2 being the above described first level of recursion), it will always use inverse plurality. If the depth is even, it will use regular plurality. (notice that there doesn't appear to be any different results with odd vs even recursion depth. It just seems to get more accurate at greater depth)
Let me know if any of this helps, or if you want me to try to put it in another language or form.
-
You propose recursive application of Hare. Recursion could also be applied to other IRV variants. I don't know whether they produce "better" results or converge faster.
-
@jack-waugh said in Recursive IRV:
Recursion could also be applied to other IRV variants.
Which IRV variants? Just curious.
The algorithm I currently have could work with various differences, such as instead of doing plurality as the last step, it does something like Score or Borda count. Or considering that the winner is the one with the least last place votes.
My hypothesis, far from proven, is that they would all converge to the same result. If that were actually proven, that would be pretty notable, I'd think.
-
Bottom-two Runoff and Reverse STAR.
Short of a formal proof, we could try some examples and see whether they conform to your hypothesis that the variants and recursive Hare converge to the same results.