STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?)
-
@Jack-Waugh said in STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?):
This throws away all the information about how strongly voters strategically support a candidate who falls in order between two others
Yes I believe this information SHOULD be thrown away except to resolve a Condorcet cycle.
This is exactly why STAR throws away strength of preference (between the two front runners) as its final step.
This in itself is probably a topic in its own, since your complaint applies to all Condorcet systems. There is good reason they throw away this information.
Remember, most of us consider that, if only two candidates are running, the one that has the majority should win. (right?) This also ignores strength of preference. That's on purpose, and is consistent with the idea of "one person one vote."
Generalizing further, let's look at a particularly "pure" example of why we want to do this. Say you are voting for the temperature to set the thermostat to (such as in an open office). Should the person who likes it at 95 degrees have more "pull" than the (also warm-preferring) person who likes it at 74 degrees? I say no. Strength of preference shouldn't matter, all that matters is whether their preference is above or below the median. See my demonstration of this at: https://pianop.ly/voting/median.html
Anyway, I will bring this up as a different topic where, instead of discussing it relative to one Condorcet method, we discuss it relative to all Condorcet methods or methods that tend to favor the Condorcet winner (or more generally, select the candidate that is "first choice of the median voter").
-
@Toby-Pereira said in STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?):
It seems to me that you want to find the simplest Condorcet method, ...
More or less. I want a more marketable Condorcet method. I'm not even 100% set on Condorcet, I'd be mostly happy with STAR if it had momentum but I think it is failing to gain traction. Simplicity is part of it, but simplicity isn't all that simple. For instance Approval voting is simple to explain the mechanics, but a lot harder to explain why it is good (such as how it avoids vote splitting, or why it conforms to the concept of "one person one vote"), or to explain how to strategically vote with imperfect information, etc.
I think cardinal ballots (0 - 5) are an improvement over ranked ballots, based on my long experience designing "cognitively efficient" UIs. Even if you are only using them for ranking, I think it is a better UI, especially for paper ballots as opposed to voting on a computer screen. In that sense, I think STAR is on the right track. I just think it gives too much emphasis to cardinal data when the ordinal is enough 99% of the time.
I am actually looking for a method that I think I can explain well, using some graphics and animation. Something I think I could explain to a voting theory newb in 20 seconds. I don't think I could do that with, for instance, ranked pairs.
I've looked at your example ballot sets, and have given them some thought. I think I'll address them soon in a different thread, since I think the issues are more general than applying to just this method.
-
Reverse STAR seems to compete well with Ranked Robin in regard to communicability to the public.
-
Can we show that reverse STAR never provides an incentive to invert ranks?
In fact, I have heard it repeated, including from WDS, I think, that Score never provides an incentive to invert ranks. But I don't actually know how to prove that.
-
@jack-waugh I don't know but whenever people use words like "never" I find myself not caring. Too black and white.
Is Reverse-STAR likely to provide a significant incentive to such strategic voting behavior? By making it nuanced with words like "likely" and "significant", it becomes a far more meaningful question.
(And I doubt it is likely to provide a significant incentive)
-
@jack-waugh said in STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?):
Can we show that reverse STAR never provides an incentive to invert ranks?
Never? No, because it isn't true. The following example is effective at showing this for many Condorcet methods. (Not all, but many.)
40 A5 > B3 > C0
25 B5 > A3> C0
35 C5 > B3 > A0
A 275; B 350; C 175
B60-A40; B65-C35; A65-C35
B is a Condorcet winner and a score winner.
If 26 A voters lower B to 0, A will win the score vote, but B will still be a Condorcet winner. (At least 30 A voters must bury B to 0 to make B not a Condorcet winner just by burying B.)
However, if these 26 A voters also give C a point, then there is a Condorcet cycle, and so A wins.26 A5 > C1 > B0
14 A5 > B3 > C0
25 B5 > A3 > C0
35 C5 > B3 > A0
A 275; B 272; C 201
B60-A40; C61-B39; A65-C35However, I don't think this example is terribly damning because B voters only have to reciprocate a little to get back to winning. Although I do wish sorted margins was easier to explain because it is quite strong against this kind of strategy.
Edit:
@rob said in STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?):(BTW you made an error on the second line, you meant C0 not A0)
Fixed.
-
@marylander It's an interesting example, although I agree it isn't "terribly damning" because, well, I just can't imagine anyone in a real world election trying to use that strategy because they'd have to be extremely knowledgeable about how others are going to vote, to not risk doing more harm than good. (i.e. giving the election to C, who they like the least)
In theory, we could alter the method to (after narrowing the field to the ones that have the most pairwise wins) then narrow it to the top two score winners, then choose the pairwise winner from those two. So then it would be even more like STAR, but with the pairwise step at the beginning.
26: A[5] C[1] B[0] 14: A[5] B[3] C[0] 25: B[5] A[3] C[0] 35: C[5] B[3] A[0] ****** Pairwise wins ****** A: 1 B: 1 C: 1 ****** Score ****** A: 275 (2.7500) B: 272 (2.7200) C: 201 (2.0100) ****** STAR ****** B: 60 A: 40
This would give it to B, which would be the Condorcet winner if everyone voted sincerely. In this case it is basically STAR (since the pairwise step didn't actually narrow it down at all), but of course most of the time it's just gonna pick the Condorcet winner.
(BTW you made an error on the second line, you meant C0 not A0)
-
@rob Very late to this conversation but what you're describing is exactly the Dasgupta-Maskin method[1] which is just Copeland with a Borda tie breaker. This method has actually been used in figure skating competitions under the name of "one by one"[2]
There are different version of Copeland depending on how you wanna score wins, ties, and losses. Most commonly used is probably the 1/½/0 (1 point for wins, 0.5 points for ties, 0 for losses) method but Lull proposed a 1/1/0 method and 3/1/0 is commonly used in sports. But it seems like you're just using a 1/0/0 Copeland here
This system can also be compared to Black's which is essentially just Condorcet with Borda tiebreaker
[1] https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/maskin/files/voting.pdf
[2] https://sci-hub.se/10.1287/opre.2014.1269 -
Perhaps we can differentiate them like so:
star
: top two runoff based on borda score and pairwise winner for the second round
dasgupta_maskin
/one_by_one
: 1/0.5/0 copeland with borda tiebreaker
reverse_star
: 1/0/0 copeland with borda tiebreaker
black
: simple condorcet with borda tiebreaker -
@culi In Borda, you can't skip ranks, but in reverse STAR (which could be called RATS), you can.
-
@culi Well it isn't a Borda tie breaker, it is a Score tiebreaker. This method uses Cardinal ballots.
-
This may be the fairest system I have ever heard of for a single winner.
-
@jack-waugh Cool I'm not sure whether it is the absolute fairest but I like its balance of fairness (i.e. "one person one vote" or more accurately described as "everyone has equal voting power") and simplicity.
-
@rob OK, I'll bite -- what do you think is fairer, and on what grounds?
-
@jack-waugh My primary criteria for fairness is that each voter has equal pull. As you know, I've said the nearest to perfect example of this is voting for a number (such as temperature) and picking the median. If you translate that to single winner elections with a finite number of candidates, you want to make it "as Condorcet as possible." That is, you want to -- as much as possible -- ignore strength of preference. (because factoring in strength of preference incentivizes exaggeration, etc)
I have a suspicion, but I haven't confirmed it, that the "most Condorcet" method is the recursive IRV one I proposed. (https://www.votingtheory.org/forum/topic/276/recursive-irv) The deeper you recurse, the better. If you only do it one level deep, it is plain old IRV. Go one level deeper and it will make it Condorcet compliant. Go 3 or 4 levels deep, and, well, it will just keep getting more and more Condorcet-ish.
That said, this reverse STAR one is plenty good, simply by virtue of being Condorcet. A simple improvement (based on what I said above) would be to normalize the ballots of the members of the Copeland set prior to calculating scores, but that makes it more complicated and I think it is unnecessary.
-
@jack-waugh said in STAR-like method ("reverse STAR"?):
@rob OK, I'll bite -- what do you think is fairer, and on what grounds?
You're saying it's the fairest. I think the onus is on you to justify that!
-
This post is deleted! -
Paul Cohen comments on this method (I had brought it to his attention (writing under my real name, William Waugh)). One can reply in the publication he uses if one is fast enough. After a certain timeout period, it becomes impossible to add a comment to a given article without supporting the publication with money. I don't know how many or few people read his posts.
-
Maybe it should be called "LLull Then Score", abbreviated LLTS.
-
@jack-waugh He doesn't seem to understand the basics.
He says "it seems quite likely that Condorcet scoring would only result in the continuation of two-party politics," but doesn't really give any reason for coming to this conclusion.
He previously noted "Consider that in a contest between only two candidates, it is unclear what advantage Condorcet voting might have, even over plurality voting." Well, yeah, of course. If only 2 candidates, making it ranked or Condorcet or anything else won't improve it.
But the point is that, under a better system (which could be this one, IRV, Approval, STAR, or whatever), the incentives change, especially in the long term. People more in the middle have far more incentive to run. There is less incentive to eliminate similar candidates via primaries or other party nomination mechanisms. Meaning it is far more likely to have more than two viable candidates.
Parties, and especially the two major parties, will remain an important force in political elections as long as there are plurality elections. Even if the current election is done via Condorcet, you can't 100% escape the influence of parties that are mostly incentivized due to the plurality elections that are still happening. But the more you have Condorcet elections (or STAR or IRV or whatever), the less the influence by the major two parties will be.
I believe this "vote splitting resistant" effect is strongest on Condorcet methods, but it is true for all of the above methods. If he doesn't understand how this would reduce two-party domination, I would suggest he needs to do some reading before he give hot-takes.